Rave Radio: Offline (0/0)
Email: Password:
News (Media Awareness Project) - US: Book Review: Legalize It: New Book Argues for Drug-Law
Title:US: Book Review: Legalize It: New Book Argues for Drug-Law
Published On:2004-09-17
Source:B. U. Bridge (Boston U., MA Edu)
Fetched On:2008-01-17 23:57:35
LEGALIZE IT: NEW BOOK ARGUES FOR DRUG-LAW REFORM

In the long-standing argument over whether certain drugs should be
legalized, legislators and law-enforcement officials have formulated
their stance on moral, ethical, and political grounds. Economist
Jeffrey A. Miron has focused on another component of the discussion:
the economics of legalization.

Miron, a CAS economics professor, is the author of Drug War Crimes: The
Consequences of Prohibition, published by the Independent Institute
earlier this year. The book analyzes the costs of maintaining the U.S.
"war on drugs" in conjunction with the financial and social effects of
prohibition, or drug criminalization. His conclusion: legalize drugs
and bring them into the free market.

"My own particular first choice would be that it's treated like any
other commodity," he says. "Toothpaste, toaster ovens, Ben & Jerry's
ice cream, whatever."

Notwithstanding the differences between marijuana and Cherry Garcia,
Drug War Crimes doesn't deal in the morality of drug use. Instead,
Miron weighs the efficacy of prohibition against its costs, effects,
and unintended consequences to determine whether the war on drugs is
actually worth fighting.

"One of the critical questions is whether, or to what degree,
prohibition actually reduces the use of a commodity that you're
prohibiting," Miron says. "The standard assumption behind prohibition
is that if you prohibit it, people won't do it. That's obviously not
quite right."

Since a demand for illegal drugs exists, Miron argues in the book,
prohibition does not actually eliminate the market; it merely forces
it underground. The resulting black-market operation, lacking
regulatory agencies or quality control, breeds additional crime and
violence, since "business" disputes are resolved without the police or
lawyers. The government then has to devote additional resources -- $35
billion annually -- to stopping drug-related crime and prosecuting
drug-related offenses, Miron says.

Conversely, he argues, if drugs were sold legally, the violent crimes
perpetuated by the black-market model would decrease, lowering the
government's drug-related expenses. Quality regulations would likely
reduce the deaths that result from contaminated substances. And a "sin
tax" applied to drug sales could mean an additional $5 billion to $10
billion for the government in added tax revenue, for a net savings of
$45 billion.

The work is "sort of a breakthrough" in the study of criminal justice
and drug-related violence, says David Theroux, president of the
Independent Institute, the Oakland, Calif.--based nonpartisan think
tank that encouraged Miron to compile his research into Drug War
Crimes. "It really shows a direct relationship between enforcement of
the drug laws pertaining to illicit drugs and homicide rates and so
forth," he says. "It's a significant advance, and our interest was to
pull that work together, and then pull it into a single volume."

Laurence Kotlikoff, the chairman of the CAS economics department, adds
that Miron "is one of the most knowledgeable economists in the world
on this particular issue" and that his conclusions "are worth taking
very seriously."

"The issue of drugs raises lots of economic and noneconomic issues,"
Kotlikoff says. "We have a very high crime rate in the United States
connected with drugs, and we're also spending lots of money in trying
to stop the importation of drugs."

Miron arrived at his findings after years of research, begun at the
National Bureau of Economic Research in 1988. Researchers at the
bureau were studying the economics of illegal drugs, and Miron, who
had studied macroeconomics at Swarthmore College and MIT, became
interested in the topic and started questioning the widely held belief
that many drugs should remain illegal. "An economist's natural
instincts are that things should be legal, that prohibitions do more
harm than good," Miron explains.

When he began to analyze the data surrounding illegal drugs, he found
that this economic instinct seemed to hold true. Drug-related arrests
have risen dramatically over the past two decades and now average 1.5
million a year in the United States, he says, and the Office of
National Drug Control Policy has quadrupled its funding. But drug
prices have fallen significantly over the same time period -- by as
much as 80 percent -- making them more accessible than ever and
invalidating the theory that prohibition leads to prohibitive costs.

The analysis doesn't single out drugs as a unique commodity; Miron
believes that the model applies to any limited item that is in demand,
and offers the Cold War--era trade in blue jeans in the former Soviet
Union as an example.

Drug War Crimes, however, has attracted much more attention among
prolegalization groups than might a treatise on banned denim. Miron,
who limits his activism to economic reports for the marijuana reform
groups Change the Climate and Drug Policy Forum of Massachusetts,
acknowledges that in this case, it is a challenge to keep questions of
morality completely separate from economic theory. He deals with the
dilemma by looking at the issue as scientifically as possible and
weighing the probable benefits against the probable damages.

"I think of my job as an academic, as an economist," he explains. "I
really try hard to think about all the possible consequences, and the
broad range of all the unintended and intended things that will happen
as a result of one thing or another."
Member Comments
No member comments available...