News (Media Awareness Project) - US: Milton Friedman, Free-Market Theorist, Dies at 94 |
Title: | US: Milton Friedman, Free-Market Theorist, Dies at 94 |
Published On: | 2006-11-17 |
Source: | New York Times (NY) |
Fetched On: | 2008-01-12 22:00:50 |
MILTON FRIEDMAN, FREE-MARKET THEORIST, DIES AT 94
Milton Friedman, the grandmaster of free-market economic theory in
the postwar era and a prime force in the movement of nations toward
less government and greater reliance on individual responsibility,
died yesterday. He was 94 and lived in San Francisco.
His death was confirmed by Robert Fanger, a spokesman for the Milton
and Rose D. Friedman Foundation in Indianapolis.
Conservative and liberal colleagues alike viewed Mr. Friedman, a
Nobel laureate, as one of the 20th century's leading economic
scholars, on a par with giants like John Maynard Keynes and Paul Samuelson.
Flying the flag of economic conservatism, Mr. Friedman led the
postwar challenge to the hallowed theories of Lord Keynes, the
British economist who maintained that governments had a duty to help
capitalistic economies through periods of recession and to prevent
boom times from exploding into high inflation.
In Mr. Friedman's view, government had the opposite obligation: to
keep its hands off the economy, to let the free market do its work.
He was a spiritual heir to Adam Smith, the 18th-century founder of
the science of economics and proponent of laissez-faire: that
government governs best which governs least.
The only economic lever that Mr. Friedman would allow government to
use was the one that controlled the supply of money -- a monetarist
view that had gone out of favor when he embraced it in the 1950s. He
went on to record a signal achievement, predicting the unprecedented
combination of rising unemployment and rising inflation that came to
be called stagflation. His work earned him the Nobel Memorial Prize
in Economic Science in 1976.
Rarely, colleagues said, did anyone have such impact on his own
profession and on government. Though he never served officially in
the halls of power, he was around them, as an adviser and theorist.
"Among economic scholars, Milton Friedman had no peer," Ben S.
Bernanke, the Federal Reserve chairman, said yesterday. "The direct
and indirect influences of his thinking on contemporary monetary
economics would be difficult to overstate."
Professor Friedman also fueled the rise of the Chicago School of
economics, a conservative group within the department of economics at
the University of Chicago. He and his colleagues became a
counterforce to their liberal peers at the Massachusetts Institute of
Technology and Harvard, influencing close to a dozen American winners
of the Nobel in economics.
It was not only Mr. Friedman's antistatist and free-market views that
held sway over his colleagues. There was also his willingness to
create a place where independent thinkers could be encouraged to take
unconventional stands as long as they were prepared to do battle to
support them.
"Most economics departments are like country clubs," said James J.
Heckman, a Chicago faculty member and Nobel laureate. "But at Chicago
you are only as good as your last paper."
Alan Greenspan, the former Federal Reserve chairman, said of Mr.
Friedman in an interview Tuesday: "From a longer-term point of view,
it's his academic achievements which will have lasting import. But I
would not dismiss the profound impact he has already had on the
American public's view."
To Mr. Greenspan, Mr. Friedman came along at an opportune time. The
Keynesian consensus among economists, he said -- one that had worked
well from the 1930s -- could not explain the stagflation of the 1970s.
But he also said that Mr. Friedman had made a broader political
argument: that you have to have economic freedom to have political freedom.
Mr. Friedman had a gift for communicating complicated ideas in simple
and lucid ways, and it served him well as the author or co-author of
more than a dozen books, as a columnist for Newsweek from 1966 to
1983 and even as the star of a public television series. He was a
bridge between the academic and popular worlds, and his broader
impact stemmed in large part from the fact that he was preaching a
gospel of capitalism that fit neatly into American self-perceptions.
He was pushing on an open door.
A Staunch Libertarian
As a libertarian, Mr. Friedman advocated legalizing drugs and
generally opposed public education and the state's power to license
doctors, car drivers and others. He was criticized for those views,
but he stood by them, arguing that prohibiting, regulating or
licensing human behavior either does not work or creates inefficient
bureaucracies.
Mr. Friedman insisted that unimpeded private competition produced
better results than government systems. "Try talking French with
someone who studied it in public school," he argued, "then with a
Berlitz graduate."
Once, when accused of going overboard in his antistatism, he said,
"In every generation, there's got to be somebody who goes the whole
way, and that's why I believe as I do."
In the long period of prosperity after World War II, when Keynesian
economics was riding high in the West, Mr. Friedman alone warned of
trouble ahead, asserting that policies based on Keynesian theory were
part of the problem.
Even as he was being dismissed as an economic "flat-earther," he
predicted in the 1960s that the end of the boom was at hand. Expect
unemployment to grow, he said, and inflation to rise, at the same
time. The prediction was borne out in the 1970s. It was Paul
Samuelson who labeled the phenomenon stagflation.
Mr. Friedman's analysis and prediction were regarded as a stunning
intellectual accomplishment and contributed to his earning the Nobel
for his monetary theories. He was also cited for his analyses of
consumer savings and of the causes of the Great Depression: he blamed
the Federal Reserve, accusing it of bad monetary policy and saying it
had bungled early chances for recovery. His prestige and that of the
Chicago school soared, and his analysis of the Depression changed the
way that the Fed thought about monetary policy.
Government leaders like President Ronald Reagan and Prime Minister
Margaret Thatcher of Britain were heavily influenced by his views. So
was the quietly building opposition to communism within the East bloc.
As the end of the century approached, Professor Friedman said events
had made his views seem only more valid than when he had first formed
them. One event was the fall of communism. In an introduction to the
50th-anniversary edition of Friedrich A. Hayek's book predicting
totalitarian consequences from collectivist planning, "The Road to
Serfdom," Mr. Friedman wrote it was clear that "progress could be
achieved only in an order in which government activity is limited
primarily to establishing the framework with which individuals are
free to pursue their own objectives."
"The free market is the only mechanism that has ever been discovered
for achieving participatory democracy," he said.
Professor Friedman was acknowledged to be a brilliant statistician
and logician. To his critics, however, he sometimes pushed his data
too far. To them, the debate over the advantages or disadvantages of
an unregulated free market was far from over.
Milton Friedman was born in Brooklyn on July 31, 1912, the last of
four children and only son of Jeno S. Friedman and Sarah Landau
Friedman. His parents worked briefly in New York sweatshops, then
moved their family to Rahway, N.J., where they opened a clothing store.
Mr. Friedman's father died in his son's senior year at Rahway High
School. Young Milton later waited on tables and clerked in stores to
supplement a scholarship he had earned at Rutgers University. He
entered Rutgers in 1929, the year the stock market crashed and the
Depression began.
Mr. Friedman attributed his success to "accidents": the immigration
of his teen-age parents from Czechoslovakia, enabling him to be an
American and not the citizen of a Soviet-bloc state; the skill of a
high-school geometry teacher who showed him a connection between
Keats's "Ode to a Grecian Urn" and the Pythagorean theorem, allowing
him to see mathematical beauty; the receipt of a scholarship that
enabled him to attend Rutgers and there have Arthur F. Burns and
Homer Jones as teachers.
He said Mr. Burns, who later became chairman of the Federal Reserve,
instilled in him a passion for scientific integrity and accuracy in
economics; Mr. Jones interested him in monetary policy and a graduate
school career at Chicago.
In his first economic-theory class at Chicago, he was the beneficiary
of another accident -- the fact that his last name began with an "F."
The class was seated alphabetically, and he was placed next to Rose
Director, a master's-degree candidate from Portland, Ore. That
seating arrangement shaped his whole life, he said. He married Ms.
Director six years later. And she, after becoming an important
economist in her own right, helped Mr. Friedman form his ideas and
maintain his intellectual rigor.
After he became something of a celebrity, Mr. Friedman said, many
people became reluctant to challenge him directly. "They can't come
right out and say something stinks," he said. "Rose can."
In 1998, he and his wife published a memoir, "Two Lucky People"
(University of Chicago Press), in which they reveled in "having
intellectual children throughout the world."
His wife is among his survivors. They also include a son, David, and
a daughter, Janet Martel, four grandchildren and three great-grandchildren.
A Fateful Class
That fateful class at the University of Chicago also introduced him
to Jacob Viner, regarded as a great theorist and historian of
economic thought. Professor Viner convinced Mr. Friedman that
economic theory need not be a mere set of disjointed propositions but
rather could be developed into a logical and coherent prescription for action.
Mr. Friedman won a fellowship to do his doctoral work at Columbia,
where the emphasis was on statistics and empirical evidence. He
studied there with Simon Kuznets, another American Nobel laureate.
The two turned Mr. Friedman's thesis into a book, "Income From
Independent Professional Practice." It was the first of more than a
dozen books that Mr. Friedman wrote alone or with others.
It was also the first of many "Friedman controversies." One finding
of the book was that the American Medical Association exerted
monopolistic pressure on the incomes of doctors; as a result, the
authors said, patients were unable to reap the benefits of lower fees
from any real price competition among doctors. The A.M.A., after
obtaining a galley copy of the book, challenged that conclusion and
forced the publisher to delay publication. But the authors did not
budge. The book was eventually published, unchanged.
During the first two years of World War II, Mr. Friedman was an
economist in the Treasury Department's division of taxation. "Rose
has never forgiven me for the part I played in devising and
developing withholding for the income tax," he said. "There is no
doubt that it would not have been possible to collect the amount of
taxes imposed during World War II without withholding taxes at the source.
"But it is also true," he went on, "that the existence of withholding
has made it possible for taxes to be higher after the war than they
otherwise could have been. So I have a good deal of sympathy for the
view that, however necessary withholding may have been for wartime
purposes, its existence has had some negative effects in the postwar period."
After the war, he returned to the University of Chicago, becoming a
full professor in 1948 and commencing his campaign against Keynesian
economics. Robert M. Solow of M.I.T., a Nobel laureate who often
disagreed with Mr. Friedman, called him one of "the greatest debaters
of all time." But his wisecracking style could infuriate opponents.
Mr. Samuelson, also of M.I.T., who was not above wisecracking
himself, had a standard line in his economics classes that always
brought down the house: "Just because Milton Friedman says it doesn't
mean that it's necessarily untrue."
But Professor Samuelson said he never joked in class unless he was
serious -- that his friend and opponent was, in fact, often right
when at first he sounded wrong.
Mr. Friedman's opposition to rent control after World War II, for
example, incurred the wrath of many colleagues. They took it as an
unpatriotic criticism of economic policies that had been successful
in helping the nation mobilize for war. Later, Mr. Samuelson said,
"probably 98 percent of them would agree that he was right."
In the early 1950s, Mr. Friedman started flogging a "decomposing
horse," as Mrs. Thatcher's chief economic adviser, Alan Waters, later
put it. The horse that most economists thought long dead was the
monetarist theory that the supply of money in circulation and readily
accessible in banks was the dominant force -- or in Mr. Friedman's
view, the only force -- that should be used in shaping the economy.
In the 1963 book "A Monetary History of the United States,
1867-1960," which he wrote with Anna Jacobson Schwartz, Mr. Friedman
compiled statistics to buttress his theory that recessions, as well
as the Great Depression, had been preceded by declines in the money
supply. And it was an oversupply, he argued, that caused inflation.
In the late 1960s, Mr. Friedman used his knowledge of empirical
evidence and statistics to calculate that Keynesian government
programs had the effect of constantly increasing the money supply, a
practice that over time was seriously inflationary.
Paul Krugman, a Princeton University economist and Op-Ed columnist
for The New York Times, said Mr. Friedman then managed "one of the
decisive intellectual achievements of postwar economics," predicting
the combination of rising unemployment and rising inflation that came
to be called stagflation.
In this regard, his Nobel award cited his contribution to the now
famous concept "the natural rate of unemployment." Under this thesis,
the unemployment rate cannot be driven below a certain level without
provoking an acceleration in the inflation rate. Price inflation was
linked to wage inflation, and wage inflation depended on the
inflationary expectations of employers and workers in their bargaining.
A spiral developed. Wages and prices rose until expectations came
into line with reality, usually at the natural rate of unemployment.
Once that rate is achieved, any attempt to drive down unemployment
through expansionary government policies is inflationary, according
to Mr. Friedman's thesis, which he unveiled in 1968.
For years economists have tried to pinpoint the elusive natural rate,
without much success, particularly in recent years.
Mr. Friedman was right on the big economic issue of that time --
inflation. And his prescription -- to have the governors of the
Federal Reserve System keep the money supply growing steadily without
big fluctuations -- figured in the thinking of policy makers around
the world in the 1980s.
A Retort to Kennedy
Mr. Friedman also pursued his attack on Keynesianism in a more
general way. He warned that a government allowed to regulate the
economy could not be trusted to keep its hands off individual liberties.
He had first been exposed to this line of attack through his
association with Mr. Hayek, who was predicting in the early 1940s
that communism would lead inevitably to totalitarianism and the
crushing of individual rights. In an introduction to a 1971 German
edition, Professor Friedman called Mr. Hayek's book "a revelation
particularly to the young men and women who had been in the armed
forces during the war."
"Their recent experience had enhanced their appreciation of the value
and meaning of individual freedom," he wrote.
In 1962, Mr. Friedman took on President John F. Kennedy's popular
inaugural exhortation: "Ask not what your country can do for you. Ask
what you can do for your country." In an introduction to his classic
book "Capitalism and Freedom," a collection of his writings and
lectures, he said President Kennedy had got it wrong: You should ask neither.
"What your country can do for you," Mr. Friedman said, implies that
the government is the patron, the citizen the ward; and "what you can
do for your country" assumes that the government is the master, the
citizen the servant. Rather, he said, you should ask, "What I and my
compatriots can do through government to help discharge our
individual responsibilities, to achieve our several goals and
purposes, and above all protect our freedom."
It was not that Mr. Friedman believed in no government. He is
credited with devising the negative income tax, which in a modern
variant -- the earned-income tax credit -- increases the incomes of
the working poor. He also argued that government should give the poor
vouchers to attend the private schools he thought superior to public ones.
In forums he would spar over the role of government with his more
liberal adversaries, including John Kenneth Galbraith, who was also a
longtime friend (and who died in April 2006). The two would often
share a stage, presenting a study in contrasts as much visual as
intellectual: Mr. Friedman stood 5 feet 3; Mr. Galbraith, 6 feet 8.
Though he had helped ignite the conservative rebellion after World
War II, together with intellectuals like Russell Kirk, William F.
Buckley Jr. and Ayn Rand, Mr. Friedman had little or no influence on
the administrations of Presidents Dwight D. Eisenhower, Kennedy,
Lyndon B. Johnson and Richard M. Nixon. President Nixon, in fact,
once described himself as a Keynesian.
It was frustrating period for Mr. Friedman. He said that during the
Nixon years the talk was still of urban crises solvable only by
government programs that he was convinced would make things worse, or
of environmental problems produced by "rapacious businessmen who were
expected to discharge their social responsibility instead of simply
operating their enterprises to make the most profit."
Rising With Reagan
But then, after the 1970s stagflation, with Keynesian tools seemingly
broken or outmoded, and with Ronald Reagan headed for the White
House, Mr. Friedman's hour arrived. His power and influence were
acknowledged and celebrated in Washington.
With his wife, in 1978 he brought out a best-selling general-interest
book, "Free to Choose," and went on an 18-month tour, from Hong Kong
to Ottumwa, Iowa, preaching that government regulation and
interference in the free market was the stifling bane of modern
society. The tour became the subject and Mr. Friedman the star of a
10-part PBS series, "Free to Choose," in 1980.
In 1983, having retired from teaching, he became a fellow at the
Hoover Institution at Stanford University. Five years later he was
awarded the Presidential Medal of Freedom and the National Medal of Science.
The economic expansion in the 1980s resulted from the Reagan
administration's lowered tax rates and deregulation, Professor
Friedman said. But then the tide turned again. The expansion, he
argued, was halted when President George H. W. Bush imposed a
"reverse-Reaganomics" tax increase.
What was worse, by the mid-1980s, as the finance and banking
industries began undergoing upheavals and money began shifting
unpredictably, Mr. Friedman's own monetarist predictions -- of what
would happen to the economy and inflation as a result of specific
increases in the money supply -- failed to hold up. Confidence in his
monetarism theory waned.
Prof. Robert Solow of M.I.T., a Nobel laureate himself, and other
liberal economists continued to raise questions about Mr. Friedman's
theories: Did not President Reagan, and by extension Professor
Friedman, they asked, revert to Keynesianism once in power?
"The boom that lasted from 1982 to 1990 was engineered by the Reagan
administration in a straightforward Keynesian way by rising spending
and lowered taxes, a classic case of an expansionary budget deficit,"
Mr. Solow said. "In fairness to Milton, however, it should be said
that one of the reasons for his wanting a tax reduction was to force
the spending cuts that he presumed would follow." Professor Samuelson
said that "Milton Friedman thought of himself as a man of science but
was in fact more full of passion than he knew."
Mr. Friedman remained the guiding light to American conservatives. It
was he, for example, who provided the economic theory behind
"prescriptions for action," as his onetime professor, Jacob Viner,
put it, like the landslide Republican victory in the off-year
Congressional elections of 1994.
By then Professor Friedman had grown into a giant of economics abroad
as well. He was sharply criticized for his role in providing
intellectual guidance on economic matters to the military regime in
Chile that engineered a coup in the early 1970s against the
democratically elected president, Salvador Allende. But for Mr.
Friedman that was just a bump in the road.
In Vietnam, where the Constitution was amended in 1986 to guarantee
the rights of private property, the writings of Mr. Friedman were
circulated at the highest levels of government. "Privatize," he told
Chinese scholars at a meeting at Fudan University in Shanghai; and he
told those in Moscow and elsewhere in Eastern Europe: "Speed the
conversion of state-run enterprises to private ownership." They did.
Mr. Friedman had long since ceased to be called a flat-earther by
anyone. "What was really so important about him," said W. Allen
Wallis, a former classmate and later faculty colleague at the
University of Chicago, "was his tremendous basic intelligence, his
ingenuity, perseverance -- his way of getting to the bottom of
things, of looking at them in a new way."
Milton Friedman, the grandmaster of free-market economic theory in
the postwar era and a prime force in the movement of nations toward
less government and greater reliance on individual responsibility,
died yesterday. He was 94 and lived in San Francisco.
His death was confirmed by Robert Fanger, a spokesman for the Milton
and Rose D. Friedman Foundation in Indianapolis.
Conservative and liberal colleagues alike viewed Mr. Friedman, a
Nobel laureate, as one of the 20th century's leading economic
scholars, on a par with giants like John Maynard Keynes and Paul Samuelson.
Flying the flag of economic conservatism, Mr. Friedman led the
postwar challenge to the hallowed theories of Lord Keynes, the
British economist who maintained that governments had a duty to help
capitalistic economies through periods of recession and to prevent
boom times from exploding into high inflation.
In Mr. Friedman's view, government had the opposite obligation: to
keep its hands off the economy, to let the free market do its work.
He was a spiritual heir to Adam Smith, the 18th-century founder of
the science of economics and proponent of laissez-faire: that
government governs best which governs least.
The only economic lever that Mr. Friedman would allow government to
use was the one that controlled the supply of money -- a monetarist
view that had gone out of favor when he embraced it in the 1950s. He
went on to record a signal achievement, predicting the unprecedented
combination of rising unemployment and rising inflation that came to
be called stagflation. His work earned him the Nobel Memorial Prize
in Economic Science in 1976.
Rarely, colleagues said, did anyone have such impact on his own
profession and on government. Though he never served officially in
the halls of power, he was around them, as an adviser and theorist.
"Among economic scholars, Milton Friedman had no peer," Ben S.
Bernanke, the Federal Reserve chairman, said yesterday. "The direct
and indirect influences of his thinking on contemporary monetary
economics would be difficult to overstate."
Professor Friedman also fueled the rise of the Chicago School of
economics, a conservative group within the department of economics at
the University of Chicago. He and his colleagues became a
counterforce to their liberal peers at the Massachusetts Institute of
Technology and Harvard, influencing close to a dozen American winners
of the Nobel in economics.
It was not only Mr. Friedman's antistatist and free-market views that
held sway over his colleagues. There was also his willingness to
create a place where independent thinkers could be encouraged to take
unconventional stands as long as they were prepared to do battle to
support them.
"Most economics departments are like country clubs," said James J.
Heckman, a Chicago faculty member and Nobel laureate. "But at Chicago
you are only as good as your last paper."
Alan Greenspan, the former Federal Reserve chairman, said of Mr.
Friedman in an interview Tuesday: "From a longer-term point of view,
it's his academic achievements which will have lasting import. But I
would not dismiss the profound impact he has already had on the
American public's view."
To Mr. Greenspan, Mr. Friedman came along at an opportune time. The
Keynesian consensus among economists, he said -- one that had worked
well from the 1930s -- could not explain the stagflation of the 1970s.
But he also said that Mr. Friedman had made a broader political
argument: that you have to have economic freedom to have political freedom.
Mr. Friedman had a gift for communicating complicated ideas in simple
and lucid ways, and it served him well as the author or co-author of
more than a dozen books, as a columnist for Newsweek from 1966 to
1983 and even as the star of a public television series. He was a
bridge between the academic and popular worlds, and his broader
impact stemmed in large part from the fact that he was preaching a
gospel of capitalism that fit neatly into American self-perceptions.
He was pushing on an open door.
A Staunch Libertarian
As a libertarian, Mr. Friedman advocated legalizing drugs and
generally opposed public education and the state's power to license
doctors, car drivers and others. He was criticized for those views,
but he stood by them, arguing that prohibiting, regulating or
licensing human behavior either does not work or creates inefficient
bureaucracies.
Mr. Friedman insisted that unimpeded private competition produced
better results than government systems. "Try talking French with
someone who studied it in public school," he argued, "then with a
Berlitz graduate."
Once, when accused of going overboard in his antistatism, he said,
"In every generation, there's got to be somebody who goes the whole
way, and that's why I believe as I do."
In the long period of prosperity after World War II, when Keynesian
economics was riding high in the West, Mr. Friedman alone warned of
trouble ahead, asserting that policies based on Keynesian theory were
part of the problem.
Even as he was being dismissed as an economic "flat-earther," he
predicted in the 1960s that the end of the boom was at hand. Expect
unemployment to grow, he said, and inflation to rise, at the same
time. The prediction was borne out in the 1970s. It was Paul
Samuelson who labeled the phenomenon stagflation.
Mr. Friedman's analysis and prediction were regarded as a stunning
intellectual accomplishment and contributed to his earning the Nobel
for his monetary theories. He was also cited for his analyses of
consumer savings and of the causes of the Great Depression: he blamed
the Federal Reserve, accusing it of bad monetary policy and saying it
had bungled early chances for recovery. His prestige and that of the
Chicago school soared, and his analysis of the Depression changed the
way that the Fed thought about monetary policy.
Government leaders like President Ronald Reagan and Prime Minister
Margaret Thatcher of Britain were heavily influenced by his views. So
was the quietly building opposition to communism within the East bloc.
As the end of the century approached, Professor Friedman said events
had made his views seem only more valid than when he had first formed
them. One event was the fall of communism. In an introduction to the
50th-anniversary edition of Friedrich A. Hayek's book predicting
totalitarian consequences from collectivist planning, "The Road to
Serfdom," Mr. Friedman wrote it was clear that "progress could be
achieved only in an order in which government activity is limited
primarily to establishing the framework with which individuals are
free to pursue their own objectives."
"The free market is the only mechanism that has ever been discovered
for achieving participatory democracy," he said.
Professor Friedman was acknowledged to be a brilliant statistician
and logician. To his critics, however, he sometimes pushed his data
too far. To them, the debate over the advantages or disadvantages of
an unregulated free market was far from over.
Milton Friedman was born in Brooklyn on July 31, 1912, the last of
four children and only son of Jeno S. Friedman and Sarah Landau
Friedman. His parents worked briefly in New York sweatshops, then
moved their family to Rahway, N.J., where they opened a clothing store.
Mr. Friedman's father died in his son's senior year at Rahway High
School. Young Milton later waited on tables and clerked in stores to
supplement a scholarship he had earned at Rutgers University. He
entered Rutgers in 1929, the year the stock market crashed and the
Depression began.
Mr. Friedman attributed his success to "accidents": the immigration
of his teen-age parents from Czechoslovakia, enabling him to be an
American and not the citizen of a Soviet-bloc state; the skill of a
high-school geometry teacher who showed him a connection between
Keats's "Ode to a Grecian Urn" and the Pythagorean theorem, allowing
him to see mathematical beauty; the receipt of a scholarship that
enabled him to attend Rutgers and there have Arthur F. Burns and
Homer Jones as teachers.
He said Mr. Burns, who later became chairman of the Federal Reserve,
instilled in him a passion for scientific integrity and accuracy in
economics; Mr. Jones interested him in monetary policy and a graduate
school career at Chicago.
In his first economic-theory class at Chicago, he was the beneficiary
of another accident -- the fact that his last name began with an "F."
The class was seated alphabetically, and he was placed next to Rose
Director, a master's-degree candidate from Portland, Ore. That
seating arrangement shaped his whole life, he said. He married Ms.
Director six years later. And she, after becoming an important
economist in her own right, helped Mr. Friedman form his ideas and
maintain his intellectual rigor.
After he became something of a celebrity, Mr. Friedman said, many
people became reluctant to challenge him directly. "They can't come
right out and say something stinks," he said. "Rose can."
In 1998, he and his wife published a memoir, "Two Lucky People"
(University of Chicago Press), in which they reveled in "having
intellectual children throughout the world."
His wife is among his survivors. They also include a son, David, and
a daughter, Janet Martel, four grandchildren and three great-grandchildren.
A Fateful Class
That fateful class at the University of Chicago also introduced him
to Jacob Viner, regarded as a great theorist and historian of
economic thought. Professor Viner convinced Mr. Friedman that
economic theory need not be a mere set of disjointed propositions but
rather could be developed into a logical and coherent prescription for action.
Mr. Friedman won a fellowship to do his doctoral work at Columbia,
where the emphasis was on statistics and empirical evidence. He
studied there with Simon Kuznets, another American Nobel laureate.
The two turned Mr. Friedman's thesis into a book, "Income From
Independent Professional Practice." It was the first of more than a
dozen books that Mr. Friedman wrote alone or with others.
It was also the first of many "Friedman controversies." One finding
of the book was that the American Medical Association exerted
monopolistic pressure on the incomes of doctors; as a result, the
authors said, patients were unable to reap the benefits of lower fees
from any real price competition among doctors. The A.M.A., after
obtaining a galley copy of the book, challenged that conclusion and
forced the publisher to delay publication. But the authors did not
budge. The book was eventually published, unchanged.
During the first two years of World War II, Mr. Friedman was an
economist in the Treasury Department's division of taxation. "Rose
has never forgiven me for the part I played in devising and
developing withholding for the income tax," he said. "There is no
doubt that it would not have been possible to collect the amount of
taxes imposed during World War II without withholding taxes at the source.
"But it is also true," he went on, "that the existence of withholding
has made it possible for taxes to be higher after the war than they
otherwise could have been. So I have a good deal of sympathy for the
view that, however necessary withholding may have been for wartime
purposes, its existence has had some negative effects in the postwar period."
After the war, he returned to the University of Chicago, becoming a
full professor in 1948 and commencing his campaign against Keynesian
economics. Robert M. Solow of M.I.T., a Nobel laureate who often
disagreed with Mr. Friedman, called him one of "the greatest debaters
of all time." But his wisecracking style could infuriate opponents.
Mr. Samuelson, also of M.I.T., who was not above wisecracking
himself, had a standard line in his economics classes that always
brought down the house: "Just because Milton Friedman says it doesn't
mean that it's necessarily untrue."
But Professor Samuelson said he never joked in class unless he was
serious -- that his friend and opponent was, in fact, often right
when at first he sounded wrong.
Mr. Friedman's opposition to rent control after World War II, for
example, incurred the wrath of many colleagues. They took it as an
unpatriotic criticism of economic policies that had been successful
in helping the nation mobilize for war. Later, Mr. Samuelson said,
"probably 98 percent of them would agree that he was right."
In the early 1950s, Mr. Friedman started flogging a "decomposing
horse," as Mrs. Thatcher's chief economic adviser, Alan Waters, later
put it. The horse that most economists thought long dead was the
monetarist theory that the supply of money in circulation and readily
accessible in banks was the dominant force -- or in Mr. Friedman's
view, the only force -- that should be used in shaping the economy.
In the 1963 book "A Monetary History of the United States,
1867-1960," which he wrote with Anna Jacobson Schwartz, Mr. Friedman
compiled statistics to buttress his theory that recessions, as well
as the Great Depression, had been preceded by declines in the money
supply. And it was an oversupply, he argued, that caused inflation.
In the late 1960s, Mr. Friedman used his knowledge of empirical
evidence and statistics to calculate that Keynesian government
programs had the effect of constantly increasing the money supply, a
practice that over time was seriously inflationary.
Paul Krugman, a Princeton University economist and Op-Ed columnist
for The New York Times, said Mr. Friedman then managed "one of the
decisive intellectual achievements of postwar economics," predicting
the combination of rising unemployment and rising inflation that came
to be called stagflation.
In this regard, his Nobel award cited his contribution to the now
famous concept "the natural rate of unemployment." Under this thesis,
the unemployment rate cannot be driven below a certain level without
provoking an acceleration in the inflation rate. Price inflation was
linked to wage inflation, and wage inflation depended on the
inflationary expectations of employers and workers in their bargaining.
A spiral developed. Wages and prices rose until expectations came
into line with reality, usually at the natural rate of unemployment.
Once that rate is achieved, any attempt to drive down unemployment
through expansionary government policies is inflationary, according
to Mr. Friedman's thesis, which he unveiled in 1968.
For years economists have tried to pinpoint the elusive natural rate,
without much success, particularly in recent years.
Mr. Friedman was right on the big economic issue of that time --
inflation. And his prescription -- to have the governors of the
Federal Reserve System keep the money supply growing steadily without
big fluctuations -- figured in the thinking of policy makers around
the world in the 1980s.
A Retort to Kennedy
Mr. Friedman also pursued his attack on Keynesianism in a more
general way. He warned that a government allowed to regulate the
economy could not be trusted to keep its hands off individual liberties.
He had first been exposed to this line of attack through his
association with Mr. Hayek, who was predicting in the early 1940s
that communism would lead inevitably to totalitarianism and the
crushing of individual rights. In an introduction to a 1971 German
edition, Professor Friedman called Mr. Hayek's book "a revelation
particularly to the young men and women who had been in the armed
forces during the war."
"Their recent experience had enhanced their appreciation of the value
and meaning of individual freedom," he wrote.
In 1962, Mr. Friedman took on President John F. Kennedy's popular
inaugural exhortation: "Ask not what your country can do for you. Ask
what you can do for your country." In an introduction to his classic
book "Capitalism and Freedom," a collection of his writings and
lectures, he said President Kennedy had got it wrong: You should ask neither.
"What your country can do for you," Mr. Friedman said, implies that
the government is the patron, the citizen the ward; and "what you can
do for your country" assumes that the government is the master, the
citizen the servant. Rather, he said, you should ask, "What I and my
compatriots can do through government to help discharge our
individual responsibilities, to achieve our several goals and
purposes, and above all protect our freedom."
It was not that Mr. Friedman believed in no government. He is
credited with devising the negative income tax, which in a modern
variant -- the earned-income tax credit -- increases the incomes of
the working poor. He also argued that government should give the poor
vouchers to attend the private schools he thought superior to public ones.
In forums he would spar over the role of government with his more
liberal adversaries, including John Kenneth Galbraith, who was also a
longtime friend (and who died in April 2006). The two would often
share a stage, presenting a study in contrasts as much visual as
intellectual: Mr. Friedman stood 5 feet 3; Mr. Galbraith, 6 feet 8.
Though he had helped ignite the conservative rebellion after World
War II, together with intellectuals like Russell Kirk, William F.
Buckley Jr. and Ayn Rand, Mr. Friedman had little or no influence on
the administrations of Presidents Dwight D. Eisenhower, Kennedy,
Lyndon B. Johnson and Richard M. Nixon. President Nixon, in fact,
once described himself as a Keynesian.
It was frustrating period for Mr. Friedman. He said that during the
Nixon years the talk was still of urban crises solvable only by
government programs that he was convinced would make things worse, or
of environmental problems produced by "rapacious businessmen who were
expected to discharge their social responsibility instead of simply
operating their enterprises to make the most profit."
Rising With Reagan
But then, after the 1970s stagflation, with Keynesian tools seemingly
broken or outmoded, and with Ronald Reagan headed for the White
House, Mr. Friedman's hour arrived. His power and influence were
acknowledged and celebrated in Washington.
With his wife, in 1978 he brought out a best-selling general-interest
book, "Free to Choose," and went on an 18-month tour, from Hong Kong
to Ottumwa, Iowa, preaching that government regulation and
interference in the free market was the stifling bane of modern
society. The tour became the subject and Mr. Friedman the star of a
10-part PBS series, "Free to Choose," in 1980.
In 1983, having retired from teaching, he became a fellow at the
Hoover Institution at Stanford University. Five years later he was
awarded the Presidential Medal of Freedom and the National Medal of Science.
The economic expansion in the 1980s resulted from the Reagan
administration's lowered tax rates and deregulation, Professor
Friedman said. But then the tide turned again. The expansion, he
argued, was halted when President George H. W. Bush imposed a
"reverse-Reaganomics" tax increase.
What was worse, by the mid-1980s, as the finance and banking
industries began undergoing upheavals and money began shifting
unpredictably, Mr. Friedman's own monetarist predictions -- of what
would happen to the economy and inflation as a result of specific
increases in the money supply -- failed to hold up. Confidence in his
monetarism theory waned.
Prof. Robert Solow of M.I.T., a Nobel laureate himself, and other
liberal economists continued to raise questions about Mr. Friedman's
theories: Did not President Reagan, and by extension Professor
Friedman, they asked, revert to Keynesianism once in power?
"The boom that lasted from 1982 to 1990 was engineered by the Reagan
administration in a straightforward Keynesian way by rising spending
and lowered taxes, a classic case of an expansionary budget deficit,"
Mr. Solow said. "In fairness to Milton, however, it should be said
that one of the reasons for his wanting a tax reduction was to force
the spending cuts that he presumed would follow." Professor Samuelson
said that "Milton Friedman thought of himself as a man of science but
was in fact more full of passion than he knew."
Mr. Friedman remained the guiding light to American conservatives. It
was he, for example, who provided the economic theory behind
"prescriptions for action," as his onetime professor, Jacob Viner,
put it, like the landslide Republican victory in the off-year
Congressional elections of 1994.
By then Professor Friedman had grown into a giant of economics abroad
as well. He was sharply criticized for his role in providing
intellectual guidance on economic matters to the military regime in
Chile that engineered a coup in the early 1970s against the
democratically elected president, Salvador Allende. But for Mr.
Friedman that was just a bump in the road.
In Vietnam, where the Constitution was amended in 1986 to guarantee
the rights of private property, the writings of Mr. Friedman were
circulated at the highest levels of government. "Privatize," he told
Chinese scholars at a meeting at Fudan University in Shanghai; and he
told those in Moscow and elsewhere in Eastern Europe: "Speed the
conversion of state-run enterprises to private ownership." They did.
Mr. Friedman had long since ceased to be called a flat-earther by
anyone. "What was really so important about him," said W. Allen
Wallis, a former classmate and later faculty colleague at the
University of Chicago, "was his tremendous basic intelligence, his
ingenuity, perseverance -- his way of getting to the bottom of
things, of looking at them in a new way."
Member Comments |
No member comments available...